Topic Area: Individual Transferable Quotas (ITQ) in
Fisheries
Geographic Area: Iceland
Focal Question: How successful has the introduction of ITQs
been
Sources:
(1) Arnason, Ragnar, "The Icelandic Individual Transferable Quota
System: A Descriptive Account." Marine Resource Economics.
VIII No. 3 (1993): 201-18.
Reviewer: Betsy Burleson, Colby College '96
Review:
In 1966 Iceland woke up to the crisis of overfishing in the herring
industry. Initial attempts to establish fishing quotas failed to
remedy the situation. Finally in 1972 the government established a
moratorium on catching herring. This ban lasted until 1976 when
fishing was once again permitted but under a quota system. Knowing
that the entire fleet could not reenter the market without
replicating the crisis, restrictions were based on an individual
vessel quota system.
The introduction of such a system was facilitated by Iceland's
ability in 1976 to claim ownership of its coastal oceans. As part of
the Third United Nations Conference on the Law of the Sea, countries
had consented to allow a zone of 200 miles within which the coastal
country had sovereignty. The regions became known as Exclusive
Economic Zones (EEZ) and by 1976 Iceland was one of 60 countries to
establish them. Prior to this extension of national jurisdiction,
foreign fleets had participated in depleting fisheries off the coast
of Iceland, making management of the fishing industry difficult.
After 1976, foreign competition was eliminated but the domestic
common property problem remained. Because domestic access to the fish
was unretricted, little care was taken to fish at a rate at which the
various species could replenish themselves. As a result, capital and
effort dedicated to fishing become excessive. Iceland's effort to
confront this common property dilemma, went through several stages.
Quotas were introduced at various times for different species
starting with the herring fishery then expanding to the capelin and
demerol fisheries. Finally in 1990, the government created a uniform
system of Individual Transferable Quotas (ITQ) for all Icelandic
fisheries.
Before the ITQ system, Iceland did have a management system
protecting juvenile fish. This system included equipment, location
and size limitations. The ITQ system now coexists with these previous
provisions. In the ITQ system, vessel catch quotas are shares in the
Total Allowable Catch (TAC). The quotas are divisible and
transferable. The allocation process includes a small annual charge
for enforcement. Licenses, which serve as a deterrent to entry, are
required thereby restricting access. Each licensed vessel is granted
a TAC-share which is a permanent allotment of fish. TAC shares are
completely transferable but annual vessel quotas have some
restrictions. For example, to stabilize local employment there are
restrictions on transferring quotas outside of a region. In this way
fishing rights can not be stripped from local areas.
ITQs were first implemented in Iceland in 1979 for herring. In 1990
the herring fishery ITQs were incorporated into the uniform ITQ
system without major alterations. By 1980 it was already evident that
the herring ITQ system was a success. This prompted the government to
establish a similar quota system of limited entry and individual
vessel quotas in the even more important capelin fishery. These
quotas became transferable in 1986 and were eventually incorporated
into the uniform fisheries management system in 1990. In this time,
the total quantity of capelin catches has fallen by 20 percent and
efficiency has increased with a 40 percent decrease in the number of
boats. (Arnason 1993) Thus, there are strong indications that the
efficiency of the capelin fishery has been substantially increased
since the introduction of the vessel quota system.
Introducing ITQs into Iceland's most important fishing market, the
demerol fisheries, has proved to be far harder. This industry
accounts for more than 75 percent of Iceland's total value of fishing
catches. An ITQ system was implemented for the demerol fishery in
1984 but was constantly altered before finally being incorporated
into the uniform fisheries management system of 1990. With the
extension of the exclusive fishing zone to 200 miles in 1976, came
quotas for the demerol fisheries. Gradually these quotas became
transferable but they remained ineffective. Based on the decision
that the quotas proposed by the scientific community were too
restrictive for the social climate, the government established
individual effort restrictions instead of catch restrictions. Each
vessel was limited to certain fishing days, but new fishermen were
not restricted from entering the industry. As a result, the fishing
days decreased annually for each ship in an effort to avoid an
overall increase in fishing effort as the number of vessels
increased. From a capital perspective such a system was obviously
inefficient. Finally in response to a crisis drop in demerol
population size, individual vessel quotas were established in 1984.
Arnason points out that, "The knowledge and understanding gained from
these experiments were probably crucial for the eventual acceptance
of the much more efficient ITQ system." (Arnason 1993)
Even with an ITQ system, however, policy changes continued in
response to political pressure. For example, the government again
introduced effort quotas, in 1985, to appease fishers in the
political process of increasing fishery regulation. In retrospect, it
is apparent that these effort quotas counteracted the efficiency
incentives of the ITQ system. Since the number of fishing days was
restricted, many boat owners invested in more equipment to be able to
catch more fish in a shorter period of time. When the effort quotas
were eliminated in 1990, capital expenditures fell.
While it remains to be seen how powerful a role ITQs can play in
creating a sustainable demerol fishery, the vessel quota system has
proved to have some significant advantages. First, since ITQs end
competition between vessels for a limited fish stock, these quotas
lead to a decline in wasteful overexpenditures in equipment. Second,
since fishers have private ownership of their allowable allotment of
fish, they can concentrate on minimizing costs, instead of racing to
get the largest catch in the shortest period of time. Finally, in
addition to increasing efficiency in effort and capital expenditures,
an ITQ system provides an estimate for measuring the value of the
fish stock. The market value of a fishery can be calculated by
determining the price of a quota. If the quota market is effective,
this price could roughly equate to the value of the fishery.
On the other hand, since the quota system limits quantity, quality is
left as the primary means of increasing profits in an ITQ system.
While this improves the quality of the catch, it often comes at a
cost. Discarding of lower valued fish is known as "highgrading" and
it is especially a problem in mixed fisheries like the Icelandic
demerol fisheries. Thus far, however, incidents of highgrading do not
appear to have increased significantly with the ITQ system. The
government commission, Nefnd um Motun Sjavarutvegsstefnu, released a
report in 1993 which cited a demerol discard range from one to six
percent of total catch. The report concludes that there has not been
an identifiable rise in discarding practices since the establishment
of demerol ITQs in 1984. (Arnason 1993)
Iceland implemented Individual Tradable Quotas (ITQ) for herring
fisheries in 1979. Since then, this management approach has been
broadened into other fisheries. In general, it has proven to be a
successful approach to confronting overfishing. ITQs have helped
revive the herring industry from ruin. Results are less striking in
the capelin fishery but still beneficial. For the demerol fisheries,
however, it is not as clear whether the ITQ approach will be enough
to counteract the traditional free access nature of fishing. The
fishing fleet has actually increased and aggregate fishing effort has
not gone down significantly. Since the consolidation of the ITQ
system in 1990, however, investment in capital has dropped
considerably. Iceland appears to have established an integrated
management system which goes beyond simply reacting to a crisis.
Concerns regarding increased discarding of catches and the overall
ability of ITQs to alter economic incentives still need to be
addressed but thus far, the ITQ system appears to be a positive force
in establishing a sustainable Icelandic fishing industry.