Topic Area: Water Allocation
Geographic Area: California, USA
Focal Question: What conclusions can be drawn about water
allocations and water markets in light of the California Drought
Emergency Water Banks of 1991 and 1992?
Sources:
(1) Howitt, Richard E., "Empirical Analysis of Water Market
Institutions: The 1991 California Water Market", Resource and Energy
Economics, Vol. 16, No. 4, (1994). pp. 357-371.
(2) Israel, Morris and Jay R. Lund, "Recent California Water
Transfers: Implications for Water Management", Natural Resources
Journal, Vol. 35, No. 1, (1995). pp. 1-32.
Reviewer: Peter Bingenheimer, Colby College '96
Review:
California experienced a long period of drought between 1987 and
1992. This situation became severe in 1991, and action became
necessary in order to allow for more efficient water distributions.
Thus, in 1991 and then again in 1992, the California state government
set up Drought Emergency Water Banks to facilitate the allocation of
water. These Banks were significant in that they were the first large
water transfer programs in the US set up and run by a state
government. The basic format was essentially the same for both Banks,
though they performed quite differently.
In both 1991 and 1992, the Department of Water Resources(DWR) was
given the task of establishing and operating Drought Water Banks.
They served as a broker for water transfers. Specifically, they
drafted contracts for the purchase and sales of water, and performed
as the agent through which transfers passed.
In the case of the 1991 Bank, the DWR set a fixed price for both
purchases of water by the Bank and sales of water by the Bank. The
purchase price of water was set at $100/1000m3, and the Bank bought
1,013,000m3. Half that water came from farmers who fallowed their
land and sold the water their crops would have consumed to the bank.
One-third of the water came from farmers who substituted surface
water rights with groundwater rights and sold the surface water to
the Bank. The remaining water came from surface water supplies in
Northern California that had excess water.
The sale price of water was set at $140/1000m3 by the DWR, and the
Bank sold 488,000m3. About 80% of the water sold by the 1991 Bank
went to urban municipal and industrial uses. The remaining 20% was
purchased for agricultural use. The difference between purchase price
and sale price represented the cost of water carriage. The difference
between quantity purchased and quantity sold can be accounted for in
the following way: In order to maintain water quality standards, the
Bank had to release 20-30% more water into the system than it
removed; the remaining surplus, 37% of the total water purchased, was
a result of poor planning, and was purchased from the bank by the DWR
as a backstop.
As a result of lessons learned from the 1991 Bank, the 1992 Drought
Emergency Water Bank functioned more efficiently than its
predecessor. The surplus of water that resulted in the 1991 Bank led
the DWR to change the contract system. Specifically, a dual-contract
system was implimented. Under this system, buyers and sellers who
committed to the Bank early made a deposit on the water they thought
would need or would be able to supply. This allowed the Bank to
anticipate supply and demand more accurately. Thus it was able to
avoid much of the excess supply that existed in the 1991 Bank. Other
measures intended to limit the surplus in the 1992 Bank included much
lower purchase and sale prices and a ban on water from fallowed
land.
The 1992 Drought Bank purchased water at a price of $40/1000m3. They
bought only 232,990m3 of water, 23% of that purchased in 1991. 80% of
this water came from farmers who substituted surface water with
ground water. The remaining 20% came from surpluses in Northern
California surface water supplies.
The Bank sold all the water at a price of $58/1000m3, though this
price was not officially fixed. Unlike the 1991 Bank, the majority
(60%) of this water went to agricultural uses. The Department of Fish
and Game bought 15% of the water to account for undervalued instream
uses, and the remaining 25% went to urban uses.
Many conclusions can be drawn about water transfers and water
allocations in light of the California Drought Emergency Water Banks
of 1991 and 1992. The Banks were essentially institutions designed to
transfer water from low-valued uses to high-valued uses during a
period of intense scarcity. Transfers were needed because the water
allocations during non-drought periods did not necessarily reflect
the high-valued uses during a drought. The Banks were very effective
at achieving this because they minimized transaction costs and risks.
Thus, it can be said that if transaction costs and risks can be
minimized by either the implimentation of new government policies or
the abolishment of old government policies, the water market can
operate more efficiently. One can take this further by saying that
water would be allocated more efficiently if water markets were
allowed to operate freely. That is, water would go to high-valued
uses in the absence of government regulations and laws that limit
water transfers and raise transactions costs. Specifically, riparian
rights, which are currently non-transferable in California and
elsewhere, should be made transferable. They were transferable while
the Banks were in existence, and were a major factor in the success
of the Banks. If property rights were clear, secure, and
transferable, owners of the water (or the right to the water) would
allocate it in such a way as to maximize the present value of net
benefits. This would ensure the continuity of the water supply except
in the presence of an extremely large discount rate. Some would argue
that the success of the Banks indicates a need for more government
intervention. That is a superficial conclusion, however, because the
Banks were, in a sense, temporary exceptions to policies that limit
transfers.
If the market were allowed to operate more freely, however, some
legislation would still be required in order to limit externalities.
In-stream uses which are often undervalued would need to be taken
into account. In addition, environmetal impacts that do not directly
effect the owner of the water must be accounted for with government
policy. The combination of market forces and properly targeted
policies would lead to an efficient water allocation which would be
sustainable both in terms of the water supply and the overall
environment.