Topic Area: Water Management
Geographic Area: Latin America (Mendoza, Argentina)
Focal Question: How does Mendoza's water management system
fare with external market factors?
Sources:
(1) Lee, Terrence Richard. "Managing Water Resources in Latin
America." Natural Resources Journal, Vol. 30, (1990):
581-607.
(2) Baars, E., A.P.M. Bastiaansen and M. Menenti. "A User-Oriented
and Quantifiable Approach to Irrigation Design." Water Resources
Management, Vol. 9 (1995): 95-113.
Reviewer: Tom DeCoff, Colby College '97
Review:
Water resource management in Latin America is currently problematic.
The difficulties experienced can be traced back to the initial
establishment of water rights. In the fifteenth century the Spanish
colonizers replaced the pre-existing social control of water in Latin
America with their own European-based system. The system again
changed when the countries of Latin America gained their
independence. Their newly drafted constitutions declared water to be
a public good and a function of local, provincial governments.
Mendoza, Argentina is just one province in Latin America that is
experiencing difficulties, to which Mendoza's climate is partially
responsible. The area is primarily arid, receiving less than 200
millimeters (around 7.8 inches) of rainfall annually. Four rivers are
tributaries to a river that does not even reach the sea. The northern
and central parts of Mendoza are not equipped with irrigation
regulatory structures, but the southern area has an elaborate series
of hydroelectric dams.
Despite the arid climate, Mendoza is economically reliant on
agriculture, specifically grape cultivation. It is estimated that
grapes, for wine production, constitute 75% of Mendoza's agricultural
activity. The grape dependency was powered by two distinct forces: 1)
the Mendoza-Buenos Aires railroad constructed at the end of the
nineteenth century, bringing in an influx of Spanish and Italian
grape cultivation specialists and 2) an increasing demand for wine.
By 1930, a restricted water supply was inhibiting agriculture.
The discovery and eventual exploitation of groundwater between 1930
and 1970 eased the water deficit, despite an increasing northern
demand for water for waste disposal (deviating from almost exclusive
previous use for irrigation). The water "abundance" led to prosperous
agriculture which led to sustained economic growth and high regional
incomes. This scenario created the illusion that the water management
system in Mendoza was both effective and efficient. That illusion
soon faded.
One contributory factor was a declining economy. Domestic demand for
wine had declined because of economic recession and changing consumer
preferences in favor of wine substitutes such as beer and soft
drinks. Subsequently, Mendoza's agriculture-intensive economy
suffered.
The water administration system in Mendoza worsened the economic
suffering. Water management, as a function of provincial government,
involved two branches, the Departamento General de Irrigacion (DGI)
and the Inspecciones de Cauce. The DGI is the primary branch and is
responsible for the complex of works, including the river, the
diversion structures (such as dams), the main canals and groundwater
basins. Despite being one of the oldest water management institutions
in Latin America, the DGI has had tremendous difficulties in
adjusting to the economic changes evident in Mendoza.
One such problem is the collection of revenue. The DGI collects
revenue by levying taxes on farmers. These lump sum taxes are for
water access not for usage and are economically problematic. When
farmers suffer depressed production (due to grape demand decreases,
for example) the DGI's revenue suffers, reducing its future capacity
to improve water diversion and distribution. The inability of the DGI
to effectively and efficiently provide to farmers compounds the DGI's
inability for effective water management in a positive feedback loop
fashion. Less money for the DGI today means less resources for the
DGI to provide to farmers in the future, which leads to lower farmer
productivity, which leads back to less money for the DGI.
Another problem generated by the DGI lies in groundwater regulation.
The use of groundwater is fundamentally uncontrolled and little
knowledge about its supply, quality and usage exists. Less than 1% of
DGI's staff works in the administration of groundwater.
The rigid water rights structure in Mendoza yields further
inefficiency problems. Nontransferable water rights are assigned to a
piece of land in a specific amount whether used or not. Efficiency
dictates that resources be allocated to the party that places the
highest value on the resource; Mendoza's system prevents this. Even
if the initial allocation of water were efficient, the current system
has little capacity to respond to changing circumstances.
Infrastructural problems such as bureaucratic budget controls and
primitive means of data collection and storage (registers of water
rights are maintained by hand and are separate for surface and
groundwater rights) contribute to the DGI's demonstration of
inefficient water management. Finally, the aforementioned tax system
of farmers is an inefficiency causing agent in itself. Farmers pay
for the right to use water (a flat fee) instead of paying for the
actual usage (a marginal cost). Hence farmers have no economic
rationale to conserve or to use water efficiently.
The diagnosis for the DGI's water management system in Mendoza is
unfortunately grim. Ill-defined, rigid property rights, bureaucratic
blockades and an uneconomical taxing structure plague the DGI's
ability to effectively and efficiently administer water. Although Lee
provides a prescription of better management through education and
training of staff (especially in groundwater), the recognition of
other water uses such as waste removal and a better integration of
surface water and groundwater management, these are not likely to
solve the problem as long as structural problems persist.
Baars develops a possible solution to the water rights rigidity
problem in Mendoza. Interviews with farmers reveal that farmers would
favor a water distribution system in which they could have more
influence in the way water is delivered (i.e. have influence in the
DGI's task). The maximum amount of water to be received annually
would still be determined by the DGI. The mean maximum allowance to
each farmer would essentially remain the same but would vary over the
years only in accordance with total water availability. Total water
availability would depend on snowfall in the mountainous regions. The
system proposed by Baars would allow farmers to allocate his/her
annual share of water over the successive months at their discretion.
The sole limitation would be that any one monthly allocation must be
limited to a certain volume per farmer, set by the management
structure. The farmers would still be able to claim the amount of
water to which their water right is entitled to, even if they do not
cultivate the total area on which these rights are based. They could
also economize on water costs by asking only for a volume that would
satisfy their true water needs (based on crop needs) and pay only for
what they ask for. Assuming that the costs of water are high enough
to accurately reflect scarcity, then this "pay-for-what-you-use"
system will provide incentives for water conservation and would make
water distribution more flexible as water can be delivered in
accordance with farmers' perceptions of water requirements of the
cropping patterns. Excess water supply due to better availability can
be avoided without under-supplying farms.
Baars' proposal appears to be a feasible solution to an evident
problem in Mendoza. However, this solution assumes that some of the
other problems are corrected. Knowledge of total water availability,
for example, requires the better integration of groundwater and
surface water management, a point mentioned by Lee. Additionally, the
development of this kind of system would rely heavily on the (lack
of) expertise addressed in Lee's request for better training and
information. The inefficiencies in Mendoza need to be corrected.
Baars' suggestion is a step in the right direction but other facets,
such as those mentioned by Lee, must be addressed first.