Applications:
Other
(Updated
in 3/08)
WATER
SUPPLY
Anderson,
T. L., ed. (1983). Water Rights: Scarce Resource Allocation, Bureaucracy and the Environment .
Cambridge, MA,
Ballinger Publishing Company.
Anderson,
T. L. and D. R. Leal (1988). "Going with the Flow: Marketing Instream Flows
and Groundwater." Columbia Journal of Environmental Law 13 (2): 317-324.
Bauer,
C. J. (1998). Against the Current: Privatization, Water Markets, and the State in Chile . Norwell,
MA, Kluwer Academic
Publishers.
Bauer,
C. J. (1998). "Slippery Property Rights: Multiple Water Uses and the Neoliberal
Model in Chile, 1981-1995." Natural Resources Journal 38 (1): 109-155.
Berck,
P. and J. Lipow (1994). "Real and Ideal Water Rights - The Prospects for
Water-Rights Reform in Israel, Gaza, and the West Bank." Resource and Energy Economics 16
(4): 287-301.
Bjornlund,
H. and J. McKay (2002). "Aspects of Water Markets for Developing Countries:
Experiences from Australia, Chile and the US." Environment and Development
Economics 7(4): 769-795.
Bjornlund,
H. (2004). "Formal and informal water markets: Drivers of sustainable
rural communities?" Water Resources Research 40(9).
Brennen,
D. and M. Scoccimarro (1999). "Issues in Defining Property Rights to Improve
Austrailian Water Markets." Australian Journal of Agricultural and
Resource Economics 43 (1): 69-89.
Carey,
Janis, David L. Sunding and David Zilberman (2002). "Transaction Costs and Trading Behavior in
an Immature Water
Market." Environment and Developmental Economics 7(4): 733-50.
Colby,
B. G. (1995). Regulation, Imperfect Markets, and Transactions Costs: The Elusive Quest for
Efficiency in Water
Allocation. The Handbook of Environmental Economics . D. W. Bromley. Oxford, UK,
Blackwell: 475-502.
Crase,
L., L. O'Reilly, et al. (2000). "Water Markets as a Vehicle for Water Reform:
The Case of New South Wales." 44 (2): 299-321.
Collinge,
R. A. (1994). "Transferable Rate Entitlements: The Overlooked Opportunity in
Municipal Water Pricing." Public Finance Quarterly 22 (1): 46-64.
Dandy,
G., T. Nguyen, et al. (1997). "Estimating Residential Water Demand in the
Presence of Free Allowances." Land Economics 73 (1): 125-139.
Easter,
K. W., M. W. Rosegrant, et al., Eds. (1998). Markets for Water: Potential and Performance .
Dordrecht, Kluwer
Academic Publishers.
Easter,
K. W., M. W. Rosengrant, et al. (1999). "Formal and Informal Markets for Water:
Institutions, Performance, and Constraints." World Bank Res. Observer. 14
(1): 99-116.
Fadali,
E. and W. D. Shaw (1998). "Can Recreation Values for a Lake Constitute a Market
for Banked Agricultural Water?" Contemporary Economic Policy 16(4): 433-41.
Howe,
C. W., D. R. Schurmeier, et al. (1986). "Innovative Approaches to Water
Allocation: The Potential for Water Markets." Water Resources Research 22
(4): 439-45.
Howitt,
R. E. (1994). "Empirical Analysis of Water Market Institutions - The 1991
California Water Market." Resource and Energy Economics 16 (4): 357-371.
Kraemer,
A. and K. M. Banholzer (1999). Ch. IV--Tradable Permits in Water Resource Management and Water
Pollution Control. Implementing Domestic Tradable Permits for Environmental Protection . OECD,
Organisation for Econmic Co-Operation and Development.
Livingston,
M. L. and T. A. Miller (1986). "A Framework for Analyzing the Impact of Western Instream Water
Rights on Choice
Domains: Transferability, Externalities, and Consumptive Use." Land
Economics 62 (3): 269-277.
Michelsen,
A. M. and R. A. Young (1993). "Optioning Agricultural Water Rights for Urban Water
Supplies During
Drought." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75 (November): 1010-1020.
Michelsen,
A. M. (1994). "Administrative, Institutional and Structural Characteristics of an Active Water
Market." Water
Resources Bulletin, American Water Resources Association 30 (6): 971-982.
Michelsen,
A. M., T. McGuckin, et al. (1999). "Nonprice Water Conservation Programs as a
Demand Management Tool." Journal of the American Water Resources Association 35 (3):
593-602.
Michelsen,
A. M., R. G. Taylor, et al. (1999). "Emerging Agricultural Water Conservation Price
Incentives." Journal of
Agricultural and Resource Economics 24 (1):
222-238.
Michelsen,
A. M., J. F. Booker, et al. (2000). "Expectations in Water Right Prices."
International Journal of Water Resources Development .
Morgan,
C. L., J. S. Coggins, et al. (2001). "Tradable Permits for Controlling Nitrates in
Groundwater at the Farm Level: A Conceptual Model." Journal of Agricultural
and Applied Economics 32
(2).
Murphy,
J. J. et al. (2000) "The Design of 'Smart' Water Market Institutions Using
Laboratory Experiments." Environmental Resource Economics 17 (4): 375-394.
Person,
P. and A. M. Michelsen (1994). "Determinants and Trends in Water Right Prices: An
Econometric Analysis." Laramie. U. S. DOI Geological Survey and Wyoming Water
Resources Center,
University of Wyoming. WWRC-94-06.
Provencher,
B. (1993). "A Private Property Rights Regime to Replenish a Groundwater Aquifer." Land
Economics 69 (4): 325-340.
Rahman,
H. A. A. and A. Omezinne (1996). "Aflaj Water Resources Management: Tradable Water
Rights to Improve Irrigation
Productivity in Oman." Water International 21 (2):
70-75.
Saliba,
B. C. and D. B. Bush (1987). Water Markets in Theory and Practice: Market Transfers and Public Policy
. Boulder, CO,
Westview Press.
Seung,
C. K. (1999). "Application of a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model to
Evaluate Surface Water Reallocation Policies." 29(2): 139-55.
Thobani,
M. (1997). "Formal Water Markets: Why, When, and How to Introduce Tradable Water
Rights." World Bank Research Observer 12 (2): 161-79.
Woodward,
R. T. and R. A. Kaiser (2002). "Market Structures for US Water Quality
Trading." Review of Agricultural Economics 24(2): 366-383.
Woodward,
R. T., R. A. Kaiser, et al. (2002). "The Structure and Practice of Water
Quality Trading Markets." Journal of the American Water Resources Association 38 (4):
967-979.
Yoskowitz,
D. W. (1999). "Spot Market for Water along the Texas Rio Grande: Oppoptunities
for Water Management." Natural Resources Journal 39(2): 345-55.
Zeitouni,
N., Becker, N. & Shechter, M., 1994. "Two Models of Water Market Mechanisms
with an Illustrative Application to the Middle East." Resource &Energy
Economics 16 (4): 303-330.
WATER
POLLUTION
See
the bibliography at http://ageco.tamu.edu/faculty/woodward/ET.htm
Austin,
S. (2001). "Designing a Nonpoint Source Selenium Load Trading Program." The
Harvard Environmental Law Review 25 (2):
339-403.
Bell,
Rosalyn (2002). "Capturing Benefits from Water Entitlement Trade in Salinity Affected Areas: A
Role for Trading
Houses?" Australian journal of Agricultural Resource Economics 46 (3): 347-66.
Brännlund,
R., Y. Chung, et al. (1998). "Emissions Trading and Profitability: The Swedish Pulp and Paper
Industry." Environmental & Resource Economics 12 (3): 345-356.
Crutchfield,
S. R., D. Letson, et al. (1994). "Feasibility of Point-Nonpoint Source Trading for Managing
Agricultural Pollutant
Loadings to Coastal Waters." Water Resources Research 30 (10): 2825-36.
David,
M., W. Eheart, et al. (1980). "Marketable Permits for the Control of Phosphorus
Effluent into Lake Michigan." Water Resources Research 16 (2): 263-270.
de
Lucia, R. J. (1974). An Evaluation of Marketable Effluent Permit Systems. U. S.
Environmental Protection Agency.
Eheart,
J. W. (1980). "Cost-Efficiency of Transferable Discharge Permits for the Control of B.O.D.
Discharges." Water
Resources Research 16 (6):
980-986.
Eheart,
J. W. (1987). "Cost Efficiency of Time-Varying Discharge Permit Programs for Water Quality
Management." Water
Resources Research 23 (2):
245-251.
Eheart,
J. W., J. E. Downey Brill, et al. (1983). Transferable Discharge Permits for
Control of BOD: An Overview. Buying a Better Environment: Cost-Effective Regulation
Through Permit Trading
. E. F. Joeres and M. H. David. Madison, Wis., University of Wisconsin Press: 163-195.
Faeth, P. (2000). Fertile Ground: Nutrient Trading's Potential to Cost-effectively Improve Water Quality. " Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute.
Hanley,
N. D. and I. Moffatt (1993). "Efficiency and Distributional Aspects of Market Mechanisms in
the Control of
Pollution: an Empirical Analysis." Scottish Journal of Political Economy 40 : 69-87.
Hanley,
N. D., R. Faichney, et al. (1998). "Economic and Environmental Modelling for Pollution Control in
an Estuary." Journal of Environmental Management 52 : 211-225.
Hennessy, D. A. and H.
L. Feng (2008). "When should uncertain nonpoint emissions be penalized in
a trading program?" American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90(1): 249-255.
Hoag,
D.L. and J. Hughes-Popp (1997). "The Theory and Practice of Pollution Credit Trading
in Water Quality Management." Review of Agricultural Economics 19 : 252-262.
Howe,
C. W. (1993). "Tradable Discharge Permits: Functioning, Historical Applications,
and International Potential." Colorado Journal of International Environmental Law and
Policy 4(Summer): 370-383.
Howe,
C. W. and D. R. Lee (1983). "Organizing the Receptor Side of Pollution Rights
Markets." Australian Economic Papers 22 (41): 280-289.
Industrial
Economics, I. (1984). Case Studies on the Trading of Effluent Loads: Dillon Reservoir Final Report.
Cambridge, MA,
Industrial Economics.
Jarvie,
M. and B. D. Solomon (1998). "Point-nonpoint effluent trading in watersheds: a
review and critique." Environmental Impact Assessment Review 18 (2): 135-157.
Johansson,
Robert C. (2002). "Watershed Nutrient Trading Under Asymmetric
Information." Agriculture and Resource Economics Review 31 (2): 221-32.
Kampas,
A. and B. White (2003). "Selecting Permit Allocation Rules for Agricultural
Pollution Control: A Bargaining Solution." Ecological Economics 47 (2-3): 135-147.
Kashmanian,
R. M., M. K. Podar, et al. (1995). "The use and impact of intraplant trading in the iron and
steel industry to
reduce water pollution." The Environmental Professional 17 (4): 309-315.
King,
D.M and P.J. Kuch (2003). "Will nutrient credit trading ever work? An assessment of
supply and demand problems and institutional obstacles." Environmental Law
and Review 33 : 10352-10368.
Kraemer,
A. and K. M. Banholzer (1999). Ch. IV--Tradable Permits in Water Resource Management and Water
Pollution Control. Implementing Domestic Tradable Permits for
Environmental
Protection . OECD, Organisation for Econmic Co-Operation and Development.
Malik,
A. S., D. Letson, et al. (1993). "Point/Nonpoint Source Trading of Pollution
Abatement: Choosing the Right Trading Ratio." American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 75 (4):
959-67.
Morgan,
C. L., J. S. CogginsS, et al. (2001). "Tradable Permits for Controlling Nitrates in
Groundwater at the Farm Level: A Conceptual Model." Journal of Agricultural
and Applied Economics
32(2).
O'Neil,
W. B. (1983). "Transferable Discharge Permit Trading Under Varying Stream
Conditions: A Simulation of Multiperiod Permit Market Performances on the Fox River,
Wisconsin." Water
Resources Research 19 (3):
608-612.
O'Neil,
W., David Martin, et al. (1983). "Transferable Discharge Permits and Economic Efficiency."
Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 10 (4):
346-55.
Powers,
A. (1998). "Reducing Nitrogen Pollution on Long Island Sound: Is There a Place for
Pollutant Trading?" Columbia Journal of Environmental Law 23 (2): 137-216.
Poewer,
A. (2003). "The Current Controversy Regarding TMDLs:
Contemporary
Perspectives "TMDLs And Pollutant Trading," Vermont Journal
of Environmental Law 4(1)
at
http://www.vjel.org/articles/articles/powers.html
Randall,
A. and M. Taylor (2000). "Incentive-Based Solutions to Agricultural Problems:
Recent Developments in Theory and Practice." Journal of Agricultural and
Applied Economics 32 (2): 221-34.
Sharing
the Load: Effluent Trading for Indirect Dischargers EPA Report #231-R-98-003, May
1998.available on the EPA site: http:www.epa.gov/emergingstrategies/njcip/
etdoc/home.htm
Shortle
J., R. Faichney, et al. (1998). Least Cost Pollution Allocations for Probabilistic Water Quality
Targets. S. Sorrell. Pollution for Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint Implementation .
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
Shortle,
J. S., R. Faichney, et al. (1999). "Least-cost pollution allocations for probabilistic water
quality targets to
protect salmon on the Fourth Estuary.". Pollution for Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint
Implementation . S. Sorrell and J. Skea. Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar Publishing
Limited: 211-230.
Stpehenson,
K., P. Norris, et al. (1998). "Watershed-Based Effluent Trading: The Non-pointSource
Challenge." Contemporary
Economic Policy 16(4): 412-21.
Stephenson,
K. and Shabman, L. (2001). "The Trouble with Implementing TMDLs." Regulation 24(1):
28-32.
Stephenson,
Kurt, Leonard Shabman, and Leon Geyer . (1999)."Toward an Effective Watershed-Based
Effluent Allowance
Trading System: Identifying the Statutory and Regulatory Barriers to Implementation" The
Environmental Lawyer 5(3):
775-815.
Tao,
W. e. a. (2000). "Tradable Discharge Permit System for Water Pollution: Case of the
Upper Nanpan River of China." Environmental Resource Economics 15(1): 27-38.
Woodward,
R. T. and R. A. Kaiser (2002). "Market Structures for U.S. Water Quality
Trading." Review of Agricultureal Economics 24 : 366-383.
TOXICS
Macauley,
M. K., M. D. Bowes, et al. (1992). Using Economic Incentives to Regulate Toxic Substances.
Washington, D.C.,
Resources of the Future.
Pirozzi,
E. V. (1997). "Compliance Through Alliance: Regulatory Reform and the Application
of Market-Based Incentives to the United States-Mexcian Border Region Hazardous
Waste Problem." Journal of Environmental Law and Litigation 12 (2):
337-370.
AGRICULTURE
Dietz,
F. J. and N. J. P. Hoogervorst (1991). "Towards a Sustainable and Efficient
Use of Manure in Agriculture: The Dutch Case." Environmental And Resource Economics
1(3): 313-332.
Hennessey,
D. A. and J. Roosen (1998). "Quota Transfer Assessments and Efficiency." Canadian
Journal of Agricultural
Economics 46(2): 191-200.
Johnsen,
F. H. (1993). "Economic Analyses of Measures to Control Phosphorous Run-Off from Non-point
Agricultural Sources." European Review of Agricultural Economics 20 (4):
399-418.
Kampas,
A. and B. White (2003). "Selecting Permit Allocation Rules for Agricultural
Pollution Control: A Bargaining Solution." Ecological Economics 47 (2-3): 135-147.
LataczLohmann,
U. and C. P. C. M. VanderHamsvoort (1998). "Auctions as a means of creating a market
for public goods from
agriculture." Journal of Agricultural Economics 49 (3): 334-345.
Letson,
D. (1992). "Point/Nonpoint Source Pollution Reduction Trading: An Interpretive
Survey." Natural Resources Journal 32 (2): 219-32.
Letson,
D., S. Crutchfield, et al. (1993). Point/Nonpoint Source Trading for Controlling Pollutant
Loadings to Coastal
Waters: A Feasibility Study. Theory, Modeling and Experience in the
Management of Nonpoint-Source Pollution . C. S. Russell and J. F. Shogren. Boston, Kluwer
Academic Publishers:
123-154.
Malik,
A. S., B. A. Larson, et al. (1994). "Economic Incentives for Agricultural
Nonpoint-Source Pollution Control." Water Resource Bulletin 30 (3): 471-480.
Morgan,
C. L., J. S. CogginsS, et al. (2001). "Tradable Permits for Controlling Nitrates in
Groundwater at the Farm Level: A Conceptual Model." Journal of Agricultural
and Applied Economics
32(2).
Miller,
K. A. (1996). Water Banking to Manage Supply Variability. Marginal Cost Rate Design and
Wholesale Water
Markets: Advances in the Economics of Environmental Resources . D. C. Hall. Greenwich, CT,
JAI Press. 1.
Opaluch,
J. J. and R. M. Kashmanian (1985.). "Assessing the Viability of Marketable
Permit Systems: An Application in Hazardous Waste Management." Land Economics
61 (3): 263-271.
Oppenheimer,
J. A. and C. Russell (1983). A Tempest in a Teapot: The Analysis and Evaluation of
Environmental Groups
Trading in Markets for Pollution Permits. Buying a Better Environment:
Cost-Effective Regulation Through Permit Trading . E. F. Joeres and M. H. David. Madison,
Wis., University of
Wisconsin Press: 131-148.
Randall,
A. and M. Taylor (2000). "Incentive-Based Solutions to Agricultural Problems:
Recent Developments in Theory and Practice." Journal of Agricultural and
Applied Economics 32(2):
221-34.
Rendleman,
C. M., K. A. Reinert, et al. (1995). "Market-Based Systems for Reducing
Chemical Use in Agriculture in the United States." Environmental and Resource
Economics 5(1): 51-70.
Shabman,
L, K. Stephenson and W. Shobe (2002). "Trading programs for environmental management:
reflections on the air and
water experiences." Environmental Practice 4:
153-162.
Stavins,
R. N. and Z. Willey (1983). Trading Conservation Investments in Water. Regional and State Water
Resources Planning and
Management . R. J. Charbeneau. Bethesda, MD, American Water Resources Association: 223-30.
Taylor,
C. (1975). "A Regional Market for Rights to Use Fertilizer as a Means of Achieving Water Quality
Standards." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 2: 7-17.
Teitz,
A. (1994). "Assessing Point-Source Discharge Permit Trading - Case study in
Controlling Selenium Discharges to the San Francisco Bay Estuary." Ecology Law
Quarterly 21 (1): 79-162.
Vukina,
T. and A. Wossink (2000). "Environmental Policies and Agricultural Land Values:
Evidence from the Dutch Nutrient Quota System." Land Economics 76 (3): 413-429.
Woodward,
R.T., R.A. Kaiser, and A.B. Wicks (2002). "The structure and practice of water quality trading
markets." Journal of the American Water Resources Association 38 : 967-979.
Woodward,
R.T. and R.A. Kaiser (2002). "Market structures for U.S. water quality
trading." Review of Agricultural Economics 24 : 366-383.
ENERGY
Amundsen,
E. S. and J. B. Mortensen (2001). "The Danish Green Certificate System: Some
Simple Analytical Results." Energy Economics 23 (5): 489-509.
Amundsen,
E. S. and J. Birk (2002). "Erratum to "The Danish Green Certificate System:
Some Simple Analytical Results"." Energy Economics 24 (5): 523-24.
Berry,
D. (2002). "The Market for Tradable Renewable Energy Credits." Ecological
Economics 42 (3): 369-379.
Boots,
M. (2003). "Green Certificates and Carbon Trading in the Netherlands." Energy
Policy 31 (1): 43-50.
Fleming, David. Energy and the Common Purpose, a
booklet that describes the author's system of tradable energy quotas (TEQs). TEQs are a system for rationing fuel which includes
everyone individuals, industry and the Government and which enables users
to sell any rations they do not use. Details available on line at http://www.teqs.net/index.htm.
Fristrup,
P. (2003). "Some Challenges Related to Introducing Tradable Green
Certificates." Energy Policy 31 (1): 15-19.
Langniss,
O. and R. Wiser (2003). "The Renewables Portfolio Standard in Texas: An Early
Assessment." Energy Policy 31 (6):
527-535.
Lemming,
J. (2003). "Financial Risks for Green Electricity Investors and Producers in
a Tradable Green Certificate Market." Energy Policy 31 (1): 21-32.
Lorenzoni,
A. (2003). "The Italian Green Certificates Market between Uncertainty and
Opportunities." Energy Policy 31 (1): 33-42.
Morthorst,
P. E. (2003). "A Green Certificate Market Combined with a Liberalised Power
Market." Energy Policy 31 (13):
1393-1402.
Nielsen,
L. and T. Jeppesen (2003). "Tradable Green Certificates in Selected European Countries -
Overview and
Assessment." Energy Policy 31 (1): 3-14.
Vine, E. and J. Hamrin
(2008). "Energy savings certificates: A market-based tool for reducing
greenhouse gas emissions." Energy Policy 36(1): 467-476.
MILK
Chen,
K. and K. Meilke (1998). "The Simple Analytics of Transferable Production
Quota: Implications for the Marginal Cost of Ontario Milk Production." Canadian
Journal of Agricultural
Economics 46 (1): 37-52.
FORESTRY
Chomitz,
K. (2004). "Transferable Development Rights and Forest Protection: An Exploratory
Analysis." International Regional Science Review 27 (3): 348-373.
Munn,
I. A. (1997). Marketable Harvesting Permits . Proceedings of the 26th Annual Southern Forest
Economics Workshop.
Gatlinburg, TN: 133-134.
Olschewski, R., P. C.
Benitez, et al. (2005). "How attractive are forest carbon sinks? Economic
insights into supply and demand of Certified Emission Reductions." Journal
of Forest Economics 11(2):
77-94.
DEVELOPING
AND TRANSITION COUNTRIES
Bjornlund,
H. and J. McKay (2002). "Aspects of Water Markets for Developing Countries:
Experiences from Australia, Chile and the US." Environment and Development
Economics 7(4): 769-795.
Blackman,
A. and W. Harrington (2000). "The Use of Economic incentives in Developing
Countries: Lessons froom International Experience." Journal of Environment & Development 9(1): 5-44.
Bohm,
P. and B. Carlén (2002). "A Cost-Effective Appraoch to Attracting Low -income Countries to
International
Emissions Trading: Theory and Experiments." Environmental
& Resource Economics
23 (2): 187-211.
Charan,
John (1997). "Designing Environmental Policies for India: The Use of Market
Incentives to Combat Pollution." Georgetown International Environmental
Law Review (Spring):
707-726.
Eskeland,
G. S. and E. Jimenez (1992). "Policy Instruments for Pollution Control in
Developing Countries." The World Bank Research Observer 7(2): 145-169.
Farrow,
Scott, 1999. The Duality of Taxes and Tradeable Permits: A Survey with Applications in Central
and Eastern Europe. Environmental and Development Economics 4:519-535.
Kallaste,
T. (1994). Economic Instruments for Air Pollution Control in Estonia. Economic Instruments for
Air Pollution Control
. G. Klaassen and F. R. Førsund. Boston, Kluwer Academic Publishers: 145-164.
Lyon,
R. M. (1989). "Transferable Discharge Permit Systems and Environmental Management in
Developing Countries." World Development 17 (8): 1299-1312.
O'Connor,
D. (1999). "Applying Economic Instruments in Developing Countries: From Theory to
Implementation." Environment and Development Economics 4(1):
91-110.
O'Ryan,
R. (1996). "Cost-Effective Policies to Improve Urban Air Quality in Santiago,
Chile." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 31 (3): 302-313.
Parikh,
J. K. (2000). "Linking Technology Transfer with Clean Development Mechanism
(CDM): A Developing Country Perspective." Journal of Global Environment
Engineering 6: 1-12.
Philibert,
C. (2000). "How Could Emissions Trading Benefit Developing Countries." Energy Policy 28 (13): 947-956.
Pirozzi,
E. V. (1997). "Compliance Through Alliance: Regulatory Reform and the Application
of Market-Based Incentives to the United States-Mexcian Border Region Hazardous
Waste Problem." Journal of Environmental Law and Litigation 12 (2):
337-370.
Seroa
Da Motta, R., G. D. Liebcap, et al. (1999). "Market-Based Instruments for
Environmental Policymaking in Latin America and the Caribbean: Lessons from Eleven
Countries." Environment and Development Economics 4(2): 177-201.
Solomon,
B. D. and Q. S. Ji (2002). "Local Emissions Trading in Developing Countries as a
Transitional Strategy toward
International Greenhouse Gas Yrading: A Beijing-Example."
International Journal of Environment and Pollution 18 (6): 521-540.
Zimmerman,
F. J. and M. R. Carter (1999). "A Dynamic Option Value for Institutional Change: Marketable
Property Rights in the
Sahel." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81 (2): 467-478.
Zylicz,
T. (1994). Improving Environment through Permit Trading: The Limits to a Market Approach.
International
Environmental Economics: Theories, Models, and Applications to Climate
Change, International Trade and Acidification . E. C. V. Ierland. New York, Elsevier: 283-306.
Zylicz,
T. (1995). "Cost-Effectiveness of Air Pollution Abatement in Poland." Environmental and
Resource Economics 5(2): 131-149.
Zylicz,
T. (1999). "Towards tradability of pollution permits in Poland.". Pollution
for Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint Implementation . S. Sorrell and J. Skea.
Cheltenham, UK, Edward
Elgar Publishing Limited: 124-140.
RECYCLING
Allen,
J., D. Davis, et al. (1993). "Using Coupon Incentives in Recycling Aluminum: A
Market Approach to Energy Conservation Policy." Journal of Consumer Affairs 27 (2):
300-18.
Dinan,
T. M. (1992). "Implementation Issues for Marketable Permits: A Case Study of
Newsprint." Journal of Regulatory Economics 4(1): 71-87.
Sprenger,
R.-U. (1999). "Designing a scheme for trading non-returnable beverage containers in
Germany.". Pollution for
Sale: Emissions Trading and Joint Implementation . S. Sorrell and J. Skea. Cheltenham,
UK, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited: 231-254.
LAND
USE
Bellandi,
R. L. and R. B. Hennigan (1977). "The Why and How of Transferable Development
Rights." Real Estate Review 7(2):
60-4.
Chomitz,
K. (2004). "Transferable Development Rights and Forest Protection: An Exploratory
Analysis." International Regional Science Review 27 (3): 348-373.
Danner,
J. C. (1997). "TDRs-Great Idea but Questionable Value." The Appraisal
Journal 65 (2): 133-142.
Johnston,
R. and M. Madison (1997). "From Landmarks to Landscapes: A Review of Current Practices in the
Transfer of
Development Rights." Journal of the American Planning Association 63 (3): 365-378.
Kleiner,
M. A. (1975). "The Unconstitutionality of Transferable Development Rights."
Yale Law Journal 84 (5): 1101-22.
Leon, C. D. and O. Renn
(2005). "Limiting land use for development and traffic with tradable
permits." Gaia-Ecological Perspectives for Science and Society 14(2): 135-138.
Levinson,
A. (1997). "Why Oppose TDRs? Transferable Development Rights Can Increase Overall
Development." Regional Science and Urban Economics 27 (3): 283-296.
Mills,
D. E. (1980). "Transferable Development Rights Markets." Journal of
Urban Economics 7(1): 63-74.
Note
(1977). "Urban Park Preservation Through Transferable Development Rights - Fred
F. French Investing Co. V. City of New York." Harvard Law Review 90 (3): 637-647.
Panayotou,
T. (1994). "Conservation of Biodiversity and Economic Development: The Concept of
Transferable Development
Rights." Environmental and Resouce Economics 4:
91-110.
Potts,
E. R. (1999). "EA Proposal for an Alternative to the Private Enforcement of
Environmental Regulations and Statutes Through Citizen Suits: Transferable Property
Rights in Common
Resources." San Diego Law Review 36 : 547-.
Pruetz,
R. (1993). Putting Transfer of Development Rights to Work in California . Point Arena, CA, Solano
Press books.
Pruetz,
R. (1997). Saved by Development: Preserving Environmental Areas, Farmland and Historical
Landmarks with
Transfer Development Rights . Burbank, CA, Arje Press.
Renard,
V. (1999). Ch. III--Application of Tradable Permits to Land-use Management.
Implementing Domestic Tradable Permits for Environmental Protection . OECD, Organisation
for Econmic Co-Operation and Development.
Thorsnes,
P. and G. P. W. Simons (1999). "Letting the Market Preserve Land: The Case for
Market Driven Transfer of Development Rights Program." Contemporary Economic
Policy 17 (2): 256-66.
Weber,
M. and W. Adamowicz (2002). "Tradable Land-use Rights for Cumulative
Environmental Effects Management." Canadian Public Policy - Analyse de Politiques 28 (4):
581-595.
Wright,
J. B. (1994). "Designing and Applying Conservation Easements." Journal of
the American Planning Asociation 60 (3):
380-389.
Zimmerman,
F. J. and M. R. Carter (1999). "A Dynamic Option Value for Institutional Change: Marketable
Property Rights in the
Sahel." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 81 (2): 467-478.
OUTER
SPACE
Scheraga,
J. D. (1987). "Establishing Property Rights in Outer Space." Cato Journal 6(3): 889-903.
PLANTS
Sedjo,
R. (1992). "Property Rights, Genetic Resources, and Biotechnical Change."
Journal of Law and Economics 35 (1):
199-213.
WETLANDS
Fernandez,
L. and L. Karp (1998). "Restoring Wetlands through Wetlands Mitigation
Banks." Environmental and Resource Economics 13 (3): 323-344.
King,
D., P. Scodari, et al. (1994). Expanding Opportunities for Successful Wetlands
Mitigation: The Private Market Alternative. Fort Belvoir, Virginia, Institute
of Water Resources.
Marsh,
L. l., D. R. Porter, et al., eds. (1996). Mitigation Banking: Theory and Practice . Washington, D.C.,
Island Press.
Heimlich,
Ralph E., et al. "Wetlands and Agriculture: Private Interests and Public
Benefits." Washington, D.C.: Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service,
U.S. Department of
Agriculture. Agricultural Economic Report No. 765. Available in PDF format at www.econ.ag.gov/epubs/pdf/aer765/.
Scodari,
P., L. Shabman, et al. (1996). Wetlands Credit Markets: Theory and Practice. Fort Belvoir,
Virginia, Institute of
Water Resources.
Scodari,
P., L. Shabman, et al. (1998). "Wetland Credit Sales as a Strategy for Achieving
No-Net-Loss: The Limitations of Regulatory Conditions." Wetlands 13 (3): 471-481.
HEALTH
Bailey,
I., B. Haug, et al. (2004). "Tradable Permits without Legislative Targets: a
Review of the Potential for a Permit Scheme for Sterilized Clinical Waste in the UK."
Waste Management &
Research 22 (3): 202-211.
Smith,
R. D. and J. Coast (1998). "Controlling Antimicrobial Resistance: A Proposed
Transferable Permit Market." Health Policy 43 (3): 219-232.
Sollner,
F. (1999). "Environmental Health Risks and Tradable Health Risk Permits."
Environmental & Resource Economics 14 (1): 1-18.
GLOBAL
Wiener,
J. B. (1999). "Global Environmental Regulation: Instrument Choice in Legal Context." Yale
Law Journal 108 (4): 677.
WILDLIFE
Bayon,
R. (2002). "A Bull Market in ....Woodpeckers?" The Milliken Institute Review 4(1): 30-39.
MacMillan,
D. (2004). "Tradeable Hunting Obligations - A New Approach to Regulating Red
Deer Numbers in the Scottish
Highlands?" Journal of Environmental Management 71(3): 261-270.
Rosales,
J. (2006). "Economic growth and biodiversity loss in an age of tradable
permits." Conservation Biology 20(4): 1042-1050.
INVASIVE
SPECIES
Horan,
R. D. and F. Lupi (2005). "Tradable risk permits to prevent alien species
into future introductions of invasive the Great Lakes." Ecological
Economics 52(3): 289-304.
Back to
Sustainable Development Web Page
Web
Page Created by William W. Chamberlain '98
Updated
by Christina McAlpin '99