Topic Area: Fisheries:
Geographic Area: British Columbia:
Focal Question: Are Individual Vessel Quotas Effective As
Policy Tools?
Source:
Casey, K.E., C.M. Dewees, et al. 1995. "The Effects of Individual
Vessel Quotas In the British Columbia Halibut Fishery.Ó Marine
Resource Economics, v.10(3) pp. 211-30
Reviewer: Dana Cease, Colby College Ô97
The British Columbia Halibut Fishery is one of the oldest fisheries
on the west coast of North America, with the greatest concentrations
of halibut found in the northern regions of British Columbia and
Alaska. Most of the halibut is caught with longline gear and a small
percentage with trolling line. Fishermen generally switch between
several different species during the season, most heavily relying on
the salmon fishery. Thus, the halibut fishery is looked upon as a
supplemental fishery.
Prior to the Individual Vessel Quota (IVQ) system that was
implemented in 1990, British Columbia operated under a limited entry
program with a total of 435 licensed vessels. Conversely, the U.S.
used an open-access program which, of course, created a much larger
U.S. fleet of around 4000 vessels.
These programs were regulated by both the U.S. and Canadian
governments in their respective territorial waters, and by the
International Pacific Halibut Commission (IPHC) which monitors both
waterways. The IPHC is responsible for setting the total allowable
catch (TAC), the season length, minimum and maximum size limits, and
limits on harvest limits.
Due to the enormous competition from the U.S. fleet, licensed vessels
in the British Columbian limited entry program were forced to
increase capacity with larger crews, electronic gear, more efficient
circle hooks, and automatic baiters. This promoted a frantic pace of
derby fishing, which became known as the Òrace for
fishÓ. So by 1990 the British Columbia fishing season was
reduced to 6 days from a 60 day season in 1982.
The race for fish became increasingly inefficient and dangerous, as
fishermen stayed on the water for up to 24 hours a day causing an
increase in vessel sinkings, injuries, and deaths. Budget cuts also
reduced the ability of the Department of Fisheries and Oceans (DFO)
to effectively monitor and enforce regulations.
Finally the DFO decided to form the Halibut Advisory Board (HAB) to
discuss alternative management strategies. So in November 1990, the
Minister of Fisheries announced a trial period of two years in which
to test a new Individual Vessel Quota program. The difference between
the well known Individual Transferable Quota (ITQ) program and the
IVQ program is that ITQÕs are fully transferable and divisible
by the owner of the quota, while the IVQÕs are partially
transferable and are tied to the licensed vessel.
With the start of the IVQ system, the IPHC decided that the halibut
fishery would remain open for the full eight month season from March
to October. The Commission also defined an initial allocation quota,
of which 70% was based on the vesselÕs historical catch and
the remaining 30% was based on the length of the vessel. The license
entry fees, which were required in the old system, were required in
the new IQ system as well. They served as a further barrier to
entry.
Enforcement of the new regulations of the IVQ system was funded by
the industry, through a small tax per pound of halibut caught. These
tax revenues were used to pay Halibut Fishery Officers(HFOÕs)
who monitored sailings and landings in order to validate the harvest
claims of the active vessels. Stiff fines were imposed as well as a
potential loss of quota for violations of restrictions. This loss of
quota sanction was indeed quite effective, especially during the
first two trial years of the individual quota system, because the
quotas were non-transferable. Any fisherman who lost quota was unable
to fish for the rest of that year.
In 1993, limited transferability was allowed so that quota transfers
were limited to annual leasing only, and each vessel was allowed a
maximum of four quota shares.
There were four especially unique and interesting aspects of the
British Columbian Halibut Fishery. The first was that the fishery was
in dire straits and had very little chance of long-run success. This
was in part due to the high financial and physical risk as well as
the low valued frozen halibut which generated little revenue for
small harvesters. But the worst indication was that the halibut
population had become so decimated that it was nearly unrecoverable.
The second aspect which was extremely helpful, was that the IVQ
program was a pilot program that was operated literally right next to
an open-access fishery for the same product. Economists and policy
makers alike enjoyed the ease of comparison between the IVQ program
in British Columbia and the open-access program in the Alaskan
halibut fishery. The third aspect which was previously unheard of was
that the IVQ system was virtually self-designed by the industry with
minimal outside assistance from the government or NGOÕs.
Finally, the industry showed remarkable restraint and intelligence
with their slow approach on transferability. Instead of immediately
allowing quota shares to become fully transferable and divisible, the
IVQ program tried to capture total efficiency by experimenting with
different levels of transferability.
The authors, Casey, Dewees, et al., gathered results from a survey
that they had personally conducted and also supplementary data from
the Canadian Department of Fisheries. They found that as expected,
there was a larger distribution of British Columbian vessel landings
throughout the season, which consequently spread out the supply of
halibut in the market. This in turn created a larger market for fresh
halibut, thereby increasing ex-vessel prices for halibut.
This immediate transition from the frozen halibut market to the fresh
market for halibut increased the price premiums that fishermen in the
British Columbian fishery enjoyed relative to their Alaskan
counterparts. According to the authorsÕ data, over 90% of the
British Columbian halibut was committed to the fresh market, while
almost all of the Alaskan halibut was processed in the frozen market.
In fact, the authors calculated that in 1991-93, the premium that the
fishermen in the British Columbian fishery carried over their Alaskan
counterparts increased to 70% from a 15% premium in 1988-90. Thus,
the authors conclude that Òthere was evidence of an ex-vessel
price gain associated with the individual vessel quotas of about
55%.Ó(Casey, et al., 1995)
Another result of the transition from frozen halibut to fresh halibut
was the changing structure of the processing plant industry.
Increasing numbers of small processing plants have sprung up due to
the reduced barriers to entry and the lower capitalization costs.
Fresh halibut processors tend to be more labor intensive than large
frozen processors, but donÕt need the enormous storage
facilities and freezing equipment that pervade the frozen processor
industry.
Casey, Dewees, et al. found that 44% of vessel owners reduced crew
sizes due to the new IVQ system, most likely to promote efficiency
and order. Those left unemployed were most likely reemployed in the
increasing numbers of labor intensive fresh halibut processing plants
mentioned above.
The authors also make the differentiation that the structural
adjustments taking place in the quota share system are not only based
on the price increases, but also on the new rents created by
Òthe additional values associated with cost savings, increased
security, flexibility, and control and planning capabilities
generated by the more secure property rights.Ó(Casey, et al.,
1995)
There are two major future concerns for British Columbia Halibut
Fishery; possible changes in transferability restrictions and the
introduction of IVQÕs into the Alaskan Halibut Fishery. The
current quota restrictions of four maximum quota shares per vessel
make it impossible for fishermen to make halibut fishing their sole
source of income. In other words, ÒHalibut fishing is still a
supplemental fishery to salmon.Ó(Casey, et al., 1995) The
other concern of British Columbian fishermen is that with the
entrance of the Alaskan fishery into an IVQ system, they will have no
choice but to enter into direct competition with the Alaskans in the
fresh halibut market. This will lead to lower ex-vessel prices for
fresh halibut and lower revenues for British Columbian fishermen.
However, the British Columbians will still have a cost advantage over
their Alaskan counterparts due to their lower transportation
costs.
Overall, the implementation of the individual vessel quotas in the
British Columbian halibut fishery was a success. Not only did it save
the halibut population from disaster, but it increased revenues for
fishermen and changed the structure of the halibut fishery for the
better. It has shown to be an effective control for
overcapitalization and overfishing. The success of the British
Columbian halibut fishery has given us hope that sustainable
management within fisheries can actually promote economic gain.