Topic Area: Air Pollution/Transportation
Geographic Area: Mexico City
Focal Question: Does limiting the time an automobile can be
used effectively reduce car use?
Sources:
(1) Eskeland, Gunnar S., and Feyzioglu, Tarhan. "Rationing Can
Backfire: "The 'Day Without a Car' in Mexico" The World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper 1554. December 1995.
(2) Eskeland, Gunnar S. "Attacking Air Pollution in Mexico City."
Finance and Development. 29(4), Dec. 92. pp. 28-30.
Reviewer: Kristen M. Zolla, Colby College '96
Review:
In recent years, Mexico City has found itself faced with extremely
high levels of air pollution. In fact, pollution levels in this area
constitute a health problem (Eskeland, 92 28). With the transport
sector contributing to about half of the city's total emissions, it
was clear that in an effort to combat the negative factors of air
pollution and congestion some measures had to be taken to somehow
reduce the pollution produced by automobiles.
In 1989, in an effort to alleviate congestion and pollution problems,
a new program was launched. This program consisted of a regulation
mandating that each car in Mexico City could not be driven on one
specific day (determined by license plates) during the week. This
regulation has experienced some popularity, as many people believe
that this is a reasonable sacrifice for individuals to make for the
public good. Compliance is believed to be high in light of the high
fines and highly visible police enforcement. Despite its popularity,
this regulation has been shown to be both inefficient and ineffective
in curbing automobile use. Some indicators even point to increases in
automobile usage as a result of this policy (Eskeland, 95 1).
One problem created by a regulation such as this is trips are
regulated in a manner where it is not necessarily the least important
trips which are forgone. This occurrence is an inefficient outcome.
First of all, the particular trips prohibited are not those which can
be most easily forgone, as the car owners do not decide which trips
to forgo as the abolished trips are chosen by mandate and not by
those who can measure their importance, the car users. This program
prohibits, for example, driving on a Monday. An individual may prefer
to cut back on other trips throughout the week instead of all of his
Monday trips. Therefore, since all of his marginal trips are not
likely to happen to fall on Monday a reduction caused by such a
regulation would not be efficient (Eskeland, 95).
Additional flaws in such a policy prohibit market forces from
eliminating the inefficiency. For one, trips are neither transferable
between days (as indicated above) nor are they transferable between
parties. Someone could conceivably lend out their car for a price,
but that does not necessarily imply a substitution of trips as the
lender might not have been using his car in the first place.
Additionally, since trips are not transferable, on a given day the
allocated trips are not going to their optimum uses. Two different
car owners could want to make trips of a similar length, but it is
likely that it will be the owners of the not-banned cars that will
make the trips, not those who value them the highest.
Furthermore, even if efficiency is not a requirement of this policy,
this regulation has not been shown in being effective. Eskeland and
Feyzioglu (1995, 6) modeled gasoline consumption as a function of
both gasoline prices and income. If this regulation was to have an
effect on automobile usage, then the demand function would be
expected to shift in some way, either by changing the level of
consumption without changing the price and income elasticities,
changing the elasticities without changing the level, or by affecting
both. Using data from January 1987 through December 1992 they
determined "there is a substantial change in the gasoline demand
function associated with the regulation" (Eskeland 1995 7). Both the
price and income elasticities shifted upwards after the regulation's
implementation. When data from the post-regulation was inserted into
the pre-regulation demand equation it was found that actual demand
increased after the policy in all but the first two quarters. These
findings indicate that the regulation actually had a positive
influence on gasoline consumption which is assumed to be a proxy for
total automobile usage (Eskeland, 95 7).
The fact that the regulation had the opposite effect of what was
intended turns out to be quite explainable.
One problem with attempting to control automobile usage by
prohibiting usage during certain time frames is cars are not fully
utilized, as they are not being used 24 hours a day seven hours a
week. Therefore, restricting trips that were to be taken during a
certain day could conceivably be moved to another day. This carries
with it the doubly negative effect of inconveniencing the car owner
and not reducing automobile usage. Furthermore, changing the time of
this trip could actually increase driving if the reason it was
preferred to occur on the banned day because of the convenience of
being in a closer location (Eskeland, 95 5).
Additionally, since cars are presently not fully utilized, car owners
can exchange car services to accommodate the restrictions without
lessening either's use of their vehicle significantly. One car could
do the job of two for the days when one of the two is restricted.
This could also even have the effect of increasing automobile usage
if one party were to go further out of his way to accommodate the
other. This could occur if the first party drops off and picks up
someone who would have normally have taken a direct route.
An additional problem caused by this policy of rationing car use is
that although automobile usage is not transferable, there is an upper
cost to compliance, namely the price of ownership of a new vehicle.
Eskeland and Feyzioglu (1995, 16) propose a model that explains car
ownership before and after a regulation which decreases the value of
the services a household receives from each car. One might expect if
a car is to become less useful to the owner, ownership would clearly
fall, but Eskeland and Feyzioglu's model shows that the solution is
not that simple. Theory predicts some car owners would choose to sell
if the current service value offered by owning a vehicle is only
slightly greater than the ownership costs, while others may chose to
buy. This could occur because the marginal use of the second car is
greater than previously, because it has the added effect of being
able to not only supplement but to substitute for the first car on
its banned day. The theoretical model predicts a slightly larger
number of sellers than buyers, but empirical evidence indicates that
Mexico City imported used cars from the rest of the country after the
ban.
Other factors could lessen the decrease anticipated by this
ordinance. Eskeland and Feyzioglu (1995) ascertain that if congestion
on a given day was to decrease, an individual may now choose to
travel because of the benefit of less traffic. This increase due to
improved travel conditions would be less than the original decrease,
but it does tend to offset somewhat the actual reduction.
This Mexico City experience is a perfect example of policy failure.
This regulation ignored the principles of efficiency and in doing so
overlooked the economic incentives it created. Unfortunately, this
policy created no incentives to cut back on driving and as a result
the goal of decreased car use has not been attained.