Topic Area: Pricing
Traffic Congestion
Geographic Area: London,
England
Focal Question: Is a license system effective in decreasing traffic
congestion and internalizing negative effects of congestion?
Source: Leape,
Jonathan, The London Congestion Charge, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 20, No. 4, 2006; pgs. 157-176.
Reviewer: Caroline
Allison, Colby College Ô08
Review:
Increases in traffic
congestion have resulted in an increase in pollution for cities and surrounding
communities and an increase in time loss and inefficiency to drivers. The costs of traffic congestion are
often not borne by those who cause it. As more cars enter roadways, triggering
intensified environmental impacts, the need to apply corrective measures in
heavily congested areas becomes more necessary.
London, England has recently
adopted a congestion charge for the inner-most section of the city that has
produced successful and encouraging results. In 1995 the national Department of Transport examined the costs
and benefits of a congestion charge, and concluded that a charge would indeed
internalize some of the externalities associated with driving and decrease
congestion. Prior to the
implementation of the charge, the research found that the program should be
confined to central London (about eight square miles) and should be implemented
via a license that would allow the payee to travel in and out of the ÒzoneÓ
during the course of one day, as well as park there. Charging for the license was determined to be a more effective
way to price access to central London than imposing a fare for each individual
trip during the day and/or a work-place parking levy. At the start of 2003, a five pound daily charge was imposed
on drivers who used the roads or parked their cars within central London
between 7:00am and 6:30pm, Monday through Friday (with a heavily discounted
price for individuals residing within central London). Instead of setting the congestion
charge equal to the marginal cost of the externality (as economic theory would
suggest), an analysis of household behavior and factors that influenced
decisions to use public roads or not concluded that the percentage increase of
net benefits was greatest for a range of charges between 2.50 pounds and 5
pounds. More recently (2005) the
charge was increased to 8 pounds following a similar cost/benefit
analysis.
A somewhat unique aspect of
the congestion charge in London is that instead of pricing road-use according
to peak travel hours during the day, a single flat-rate is imposed on all road
use during the day. Due to the
fact that the average speed in central London throughout the day was fairly
consistent regardless of peak-rush hour, a stable price for the license was
thought to be easier to implement than a time-of-day scheme and just as
effective. The single charge
increased the feasibility of implementing a charge by decreasing administrative
costs and making the system more efficient. The charge itself can be paid through a variety of methods
including text messages, online, kiosks, retail locations, and telephone
charges. The combination of
payment methods makes complying with the charge easier for drivers. Video cameras are used throughout
central London to enforce compliance.
The cameras register license plate numbers and match them with those
cars that have a congestion license.
The overall detection rate (considering the effectiveness of one camera
as well as the probability that each car will drive by multiple cameras) is
thought to be between 85-90 percent.
Prior to the implementation
of the congestion charge, models forecasted a decrease in miles driven within
Central London of about 20-25 percent with predicted traffic speeds expected to
increase about 2mph. The actual
results showed a larger decrease in miles driven than predicted, which has
continued to occur. Although
private vehicles decreased trips into central London by 33%, public
transportation has increased, negating some of the reduction in traffic. Fortunately public transportation is
more efficient and produces less congestion per person. Bus traffic recorded the largest
increase in public transportation.
As the number of private vehicles on congested roads decreases, buses on
those same roads become more efficient and attract consumers. As the demand for bus lines increased
and more routes and more frequent service were added more drivers have switched
from personal cars to public buses, further decreasing road congestion.
The effect of the congestion
charge on businesses within central London appears to be varied. Negative correlations have been found
between the implementation (and later increase) of the congestion charge and
some retail business sales, however, there does not appear to be a
statistically significant effect.
Furthermore many storeowners feel that the decrease in traffic is in
fact improving the image of central London and increasing sales to tourists.
Although the costs and
revenues of the congestion charge have not matched the predictions, net
revenues have been positive. The
decline in road use was sufficiently large that the revenues fell short of the
predicted revenues. Initially
compliance was low, increasing enforcement costs. The lower-than-expected net revenues triggered some
political complications because the predicted revenues were earmarked for
public transportation improvements, which were delayed as a result, thereby
placing a heavier burden on low-income individuals and families, who were then
expecting to have a better public transportation system to use as an
alternative.
The estimates of the social
benefits and costs show a clear net benefit. The considered social costs included administrative costs,
scheme operation costs, setup costs, traffic management costs, and charge-payer
compliance costs. The benefits
included time-savings and reliability benefits, reduced accidents, reduced CO2
emissions, among others. Although
the net benefits are positive, the operational costs of the program are higher
than anticipated and leave room for possible efficiency improvements. The author suggests that perhaps the
private contractor is displaying rent-seeking behavior, or some inefficient
aspects of the system may be resulting in a decrease in marginal net benefits.
Overall the congestion charge
has effectively decreased traffic congestion and emissions. Individuals are seeing a decrease in
travel time, as well as improvements in public transportation, making travel
and commuting into and within central London increasingly more efficient. The public transportation system in
London, along with the layout of the city and the significant traffic problem
were all factors that positively influenced the effectiveness of the
charge. The success of the
congestion charge in London suggests that charging for scarce road space can
increase efficiency of travel under the right conditions.